FractalPast
  • Home
  • About Me
  • Services and Rates
  • Philosophy and FAQs
  • Editing Portfolio
  • Testimonials
  • Writing and Scholarship
  • Blog
  • Contact
  • Home
  • About Me
  • Services and Rates
  • Philosophy and FAQs
  • Editing Portfolio
  • Testimonials
  • Writing and Scholarship
  • Blog
  • Contact
  • Terms and Conditions Privacy Policy


© Fractal Past

FractalPast:
​A Blog about American
​Empire, History, and Culture

Public Goods: An Introduction

12/14/2024

4 Comments

 
Recent reports that the incoming Trump administration is considering privatizing the US Postal Service (USPS)--a recurring aim for conservatives, it must be noted--prompts a reflection on what we call "public goods" in America. In my view public goods are essential to our national prosperity, to our quality of living, and to our basic rights, as I shall attempt to explain. Public goods also connect in important ways to the history of US empire. Yet our capacity to think about, consider, even discuss public goods has been severely attenuated in recent decades. 
Picture
The Roberto Clemente bridge in Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania.
Picture
Map of Erie Canal courtesy of https://www.eriecanal.org/maps.html
By public goods we mean a whole range of provisions generally provided (in liberal society) by governments, at taxpayer expense, and available of access by all. Public infrastructure such as roads, bridges, and tunnels are certainly one example. National defense, police protection, access to courts, and a monetary system constitute another category of public goods. Modern America provides other forms, such as parks (national, state, municipal), broadcast entertainment and news (e.g., PBS), or, in some communities, public pools and public beaches. Governments can and do provide access to knowledge, through public libraries, or via social, economic, and commercial statistics released by various government agencies. The air traffic control system, run by the Federal Aviation Administration, provides another kind of example. The list is varied and seemingly endless.
 
Both the American political right and left have largely removed public goods from the national conversation. The right, for largely ideological reasons, has argued heatedly since the New Deal of the 1930s (which provided so much of our contemporary public goods infrastructure) that public goods are “socialistic” and in every case inferior morally and economically to private goods. They are wasteful, deprive entrepreneurs of profit-making opportunities, and breed dependency. This has not always been the argument of American conservatism, as Alexander Hamilton’s establishment of a national banking system or the Whig Party’s championing of transportation infrastructure, such as the Erie Canal, in the 1830s-50s attests. The left, which throughout much of the 20th century has been the stalwart champion of public goods, has increasingly for the last generation or two abandoned the defense of public goods in favor of a focus on identity politics. While Democratic presidents routinely propose public goods programs (such as the Biden administration's "Build Back Better proposals, later renamed the "Inflation Reduction Act," the renaming an obvious admission of the left's inability to mount a potent articulation of public goods investments), there has been no substantial program of national investments, as such, since LBJ's Great Society. 
               
There are at least two essential arguments in favor of public goods which we’ll outline here and develop in later postings. The first is that they are almost infallibly cheaper than private goods. Public goods achieve the economies of scale that guarantee lower costs, usually of production and almost certainly of use. One publicly-financed road system is much cheaper to build and operate than a chain of private roads. A community (i.e., public) pool is much, much cheaper to build and operate than a warren of smaller, private, backyard pools. Imagine the costs, to say nothing of the complexity, if each airline operated its own air traffic control system. Economies of scale plus the absence of the profit factor (public goods are, by definition, non-profit) inarguably make public goods cheaper. A public national health care system, of the sort run by the West European nations, would be inarguably much, much less expensive to operate than the patchwork of private insurers under which the US now labors. 
               
The second, and I think more important, argument in favor of public goods is that, as the economists say, they are "non-exclusive." That is, individuals cannot be kept from their use by their relative strength in the market. Put another, and I think better way, public goods are those goods to which citizens have access by right. It is an American’s right to use a public park, or the interstate highway, or a community pool. The provision of a public good, by definition, represents the extension of rights. By contrast, few of us would argue that a citizen has a right to an automobile or a pair of jeans; the price is the mechanism by which an individual registers the strength of his or her desire for a private good to which he or she does not otherwise have a right. A toll may be imposed on a public good for some reason, and in contemporary society those tolls do in fact operate as a price mechanism: If you don’t pay the entrance fee, you can’t enter Yellowstone Park. Still, the distinction between price and toll is an important one, especially as it concerns rights. If you have the toll-–which after all is generally kept as low as possible-–you cannot be denied use of a public good. In contrast, even if you have the price–-which by definition is kept as high as possible-—you could still be thrown out of the Apple store. This principle was one of the underlying premises of Jim Crow racist exclusion, for example.

There are two legitimate counter-arguments to public goods. The first is that they breed corruption. Sweetheart deals between public authorizing agencies and private contractors have defined the history of public goods in America, going all the way back to the Whig years, and before. A robust system of public accounting is always necessary to ensure that the taxpayers get bang for their buck, and advocates of public goods should not gloss this issue. The second, perhaps even more troubling problem with public goods, is that, just as with private goods, they are amenable to racist exclusionary practice. Scores of historians have documented the ways in which politically disempowered groups, notably African Americans, have had communities, neighborhoods, and homesteads razed and displaced for the benefit of roads, bridges, and parks. The interstate highway system of the 1950s displaced Black communities in Chicago, Detroit, Pittsburgh, and many other places in the 1950s and 60s. Robert Caro's great biography of Robert Moses, The Power Broker, undoubtedly the greatest purveyor of public goods in the 20th century, details countless such examples in greater New York City alone.   

               
So public goods do not produce consensus in American life. Americans have always fought over public goods. Fierce battles over infrastructure, from the Whiggish heyday to the New Deal, have defined eras in American politics, and those epic struggles have given way to even more transcendent ideological struggles in our day over public versus private goods. And throughout our history, local but no less fierce debates have occurred about what sort of public goods might be built and where they should be located. 
               
Nevertheless there is reason to believe that public goods might get us beyond what is by now a very stale political polarization in American politics. A return to a public goods discourse would certainly re-energize and refocus the left. It also has the potential to provide political valences, and thus consensus, with a reformed right. Conservatives may decry public goods in general, but local communities still want bridges, hospitals, and parks. A more robust argument will have to be made, but schools and post offices are generally much wanted as well. More pertinently, Americans are always covetous of their rights. And a more effective conversation around public goods as they extend our rights, and hence our freedoms, may yet avail. The discussion about rights is a historic sweet spot in American politics, an idea around which many of us, regardless of where we fall on the political spectrum, might rally. It’s worth talking about.

Here's another brief discussion of the value of public goods: 
‘Public goods’ made America great and can do so again.
 
Expect to see much more about #publicgoods on the FractalPast blog as we develop the conversation. Share your thoughts below! 

Suggested reading:
Robert Caro, The Power Broker: Robert Moses and the Fall of New York (Penguin, 1975): 
​
The Power Broker by Robert A. Caro: 9780394720241 | PenguinRandomHouse.com: Books
​


4 Comments
L. Marvin
12/16/2024 09:48:47 am

Unfortunately there's nothing here upon I disagree or to present a counter argument. In fact I find this particular thread more crucial and timely than your discussions of empire. Because the latter is a "beer and pizza" argument whereas this one is something we really need to pay attention to. I'm reminded of the erosion of public goods everytime I try to find a water fountain in a building. They used to exist everywhere but bottled water and eeking out more profit or lessening cost has made them scarcer than hen's teeth in both large buildings used by the public (malls, or the equivalent) and even gov't or institutional buildings. So everyone either buys water priced more than gasoline per ounce in plastic bottles that are unlikely to get recycled or carries around some stupid steel or plastic canteen as if they're in the desert. Sorry about the diatribe here; but what I mean to say is the subject of public goods and how we're losing out is quite worthy of continued discussion.

Reply
David J. Snyder
12/16/2024 02:54:50 pm

Of course I don't quite concur that the discussion of empire is purely academic. For Americans, all questions of war and peace, for example, to say nothing of American views about what constitutes a good life, or reasonable expectations of treatment in the international realm, or the proper social order, or cultural breakdown, etc., are premised on, and occur within, a deep and historically abiding imperial sensibility. Only because we've come to expect a certain orientation to the external world do we understand many developments in the domestic world, you might say. Nevertheless, I am gratified that you've found at least one area on which to agree with me! The distinction between private and public realms is also crucially important to understanding empire (and vice versa), so expect plenty more opportunities for disagreement in the future! ;)

Reply
L. Marvin
12/16/2024 03:42:20 pm

I'm sure we agree on many more things than we don't; but I want to ensure your ideas get a thorough once-over since you're putting them in the public sphere. Nothing worse than to be a Luther nailing up the 95 Theses, only to be ignored by his colleagues.

I'm genuinely excited to hear more about the "Public Goods" thread--you've really touched a nerve for me with that. We should be very concerned about that. I'm most curious as to how you'll tie that into empire. Having a postal service and public water supplies aren't necessarily "imperial" even if ancient Rome say, had a simulacra of the former and a penchant for reasonably clean water for large urban areas. But I'll keep an open mind.

Does that mean I'm less enamored about your ideas about American Imperialism? I'm just wondering who you're trying to convince--I'm already convinced! We're an empire--but so what? Why should John Q. Public care, or accept your premise? And I offer those questions in the friendliest of ways--like over a 2nd beer in a friendly waterhole.

Great Man theories? With that I disagree, though to belabor it too much is unfair, since that was a very small tangent of what you're trying to accomplish with this blog.

Reply
O Seipp
1/1/2025 02:37:23 pm

The method in which you conveyed your ideas concerning public vs. private goods in American society was incredibly thoughtful. You not only were able to reflect on how public goods can help lower costs and complexities as opposed to private goods, but you provided clear pros and cons to each side as well. Overall, this was very well written.

Reply



Leave a Reply.

    Author

    I am an editor and historian of US history, diplomacy, and international relations.

    Archives

    June 2025
    March 2025
    February 2025
    January 2025
    December 2024
    November 2024

    Categories

    All
    Americanization
    Book Reviews
    Democracy
    Editing
    Empire
    Empire Culture
    Empire Frontiers
    Empire Ideology
    Empire Theory
    Pop Culture
    Public Goods
    Race
    Scholarship
    War And Military

    RSS Feed

    Why empire?

    This blog presents new scholarship on American empire, places the American experience in a broader and global imperial context, explores imperial habits throughout American society and culture, uncovers the imperial connections between the foreign and the domestic, and develops “empire” as a critical perspective.
    At least two features in the American experience are clarified through the lens of American empire: First, we better understand persistent social inequities in a nation professing a fundamental commitment to equality. Second, even a cursory glance at American history makes plain the chronic violence at the center of US foreign policy, which frequently mounts or supports bloody military conflict abroad. Empire helps us recognize how and why the United States seems to be constantly at war--including often with itself--with all the foreign and domestic consequences thereof.

© Fractal Past

Privacy Policy
  • Home
  • About Me
  • Services and Rates
  • Philosophy and FAQs
  • Editing Portfolio
  • Testimonials
  • Writing and Scholarship
  • Blog
  • Contact